Solid Gains in Part-Time, Low Wage Jobs in March

April 5, 2014

Yesterday’s employment report  provided solid evidence of improvement in the jobs market.  While the establishment survey found that 192,000 jobs were added in March, the “employment level” in the household survey rose by an even more impressive 476,000.  But before you conclude that the good times are beginning to roll again, you need to look a little deeper. 

Of those 192,ooo jobs that were added, 29,000 were temp jobs in “business and professional services” and 30,000 were in food and drinking establishments – mostly low wage jobs.  19,000 health care jobs were added, but these too were in the low wage areas of that field.  Manufacturing actually lost 1,000 jobs. 

And, of the 476,000 increase in the employment level in the household survey, 365,000 were part-time jobs. 

There’s another point that needs to be made regarding the employment level.  It’s now at the same level as June 2008, which means all of the jobs lost during the recession from that point have now been recovered.  The problem is that the population has grown by 13.4 million since then.  Since approximately 50% of the population is part of the labor force, that means that 6.7 million workers are now unemployed as a direct consequence of population growth.

A high unemployment rate holds down wages and benefits.  Why give you a raise when there are over 15 million people out there (those 6.7 million plus another 8 million or so who are still unemployed) who are probably willing to do your job for even less?  So, contrary to what economists are telling us – that we need to increase immigration to get the economy going again – it’s clear that immigration and population growth are a net drag on household incomes.  It fattens corporate bottom lines, of course, but doesn’t help your bottom line one bit. 

And, let’s not forget that while the employment level is near pre-recession levels, we now have 6.7% unemployment vs. 4.7% in November of 2007 when Lehman Bros. collapsed and the Great Recession began.  Truth be told, were it not for the new post-recession phenomenon of the “mysteriously vanishing labor force” (people who the government would have us believe have chosen to drop out of the labor force, apparently no longer needing a source of income), unemployment would actually be 9.7% (or 17.3%, if you include part-time workers who really need full-time work). 

Prior to the recession, per capita employment was at 48.4% with a much higher percentage of full-time workers.  At the depth of the recession, per capita employment fell to 44.9%.  By March it has risen only 0.9% to 45.8%, and a much higher percentage are now working part-time.  Now the jobs picture doesn’t seem as bright as the headline numbers would have you believe. 

 


Manufactured Exports Fall in February, Lag President’s Goal by Record Margin

April 3, 2014

http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/international/trade/2014/pdf/trad0214.pdf

As announced by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) this morning, the nation’s trade deficit rose in February to $42.3 billion.  Not mentioned in the report (because the BEA doesn’t even track it, but can be derived through some simple math) is the fact that a $0.7 billion decline in manufactured exports contributed to the rise in the deficit. 

Exports of manufactured goods, at $108.7 billion in February,  have not risen in two years, actually falling by $0.1 billion from February, 2012.  In January, 2010 the president set a goal of doubling exports in five years, the implication being that the growth would occur in manufactured goods as a cornerstone of his economic “plan” to grow manufacturing jobs.  February’s exports lagged the president’s goal by $42.6 billion – a record margin which, once again, exceeds the entire trade deficit.  Here’s a chart of the balance of trade in manufactured goods, followed by a chart of the deficit in manufactured goods:  Manf’d exports vs. goal      Manf’d Goods Balance of Trade.

The point is that the president’s failure was inevitable because neither he nor anyone in the U.S. has any control whatsoever over exports, which are determined solely by foreign demand for U.S. goods.  Cajoling our trade partners into buying more U.S. goods has been a strategy tried and failed by presidents for decades.  Federal programs designed to help manufacturers improve efficiency and to fund research don’t work either, since foreign manufacturers are working just as hard to improve efficiency. 

And it’s equally predictable that the trade deficit isn’t just magically curing itself as other nations develop into more western-style consumers, as economists have long predicted.  Global trade imbalances have nothing to do with any of these things.  They are driven almost entirely by differences in population density, as badly overpopulated nations, crippled by endemic low per capita consumption, rely ever more heavily on manufacturing for export to employ their bloated labor forces.  And American workers pay the price for their overpopulation – a problem they had no role in causing and are powerless to remedy. 

Applied in appropriate situations, like between reasonably populated nations, free trade works just fine.  But U.S. trade policy fails to account for the limitations of free trade, and applies it blindly to situations where it’s guaranteed to fail.  In the final analysis, globalization and free trade, as they are currently applied, constitute nothing more than a poverty-sharing program, conceived in the wake of World War II as a means of heading off the kind of social unrest that arises from high unemployment in overpopulated nations like Germany and Japan.


America’s Worst Trading “Partners”

April 2, 2014

The word “trade” implies a mutually beneficial exchange of goods and services.  I buy stuff from you and, in return, you buy stuff from me.  A good trading partner is a nation that buys (imports) as much as it sells (exports).  A bad trade relationship is one in which a nation sells (or exports) while buying little in return.  Such a relationship isn’t mutually beneficial.  In such a relationship, one nation creates jobs at the other’s expense and drains funds away from the other’s economy.

America’s free trade policy has resulted in both good and bad trade relationships.  On balance, its many beneficial trade relationships have been more than offset by a minority of really bad ones.  But what’s the best way to judge?  Some differences in trade imbalances are due to a huge disparity in the size of nations.  Is a big nation that maintains a large trade surplus with the U.S. any better than a tiny nation with a proportionately large imbalance?  The only way to judge such imbalances fairly is to express them in per capita terms.  That is, how much does each person in that nation buy from the U.S. vs. how much they manufacture and sell to us? 

When expressed in per capita terms, the results are surprising.  Here’s the list:  Top 20 Deficits, 2012.  The key take-aways from this list are as follows:

  • Note the population density of the nations on this list.  By comparison, the population density of the U.S. is approximately 86 people per square mile.  Eighteen of these twenty nations are more densely populated than the U.S.  Eight are more than five times as densely populated.  In fact, the average population density of the nations on this list is 493 people per square mile – more than five times the density of the U.S.  Only two are less densely populated – Sweden and Finland.  When I first published this list in 2006 in Five Short Blasts, Sweden ranked number two.  By 2012, they have fallen to number eleven.  And their surplus with the U.S. has been reduced by half. 
  • Note the “per capita purchasing power parity (PPP)” of the nations on this list.  By comparison, U.S. PPP is approximately $48,500.  Most of the nations on this list are relatively wealthy nations, debunking the myth that trade deficits are caused by low wages.  If low wages are to blame, how do you explain the presence of Ireland, Switzerland, Taiwan, Denmark, Germany, Japan and Austria (among others) in the top ten of this list?  Also, the PPP of this list has risen dramatically in the past six years.  (More on this topic in a later post.)
  • Though China gets all of the attention for its massive trade deficit with the U.S., it barely makes the top 20 list, coming in at number 18.  It has risen only one place on this list since 2006.  In per capita terms, its trade imbalance with the U.S. is rather unremarkable relative to the other nations on this list.  In fact, when you understand the role that population density plays in driving trade imbalances, the huge trade deficit with China, given its sheer size and enormous population, is exactly what should have been expected. 

People who live in overcrowded conditions buy fewer products because they have no room to utilize them.  They buy or rent smaller homes because there is no room for larger homes.  They own fewer cars because their roads are choked with traffic and they choose mass transit instead.  Because their homes are smaller, they buy less furniture, far less lawn and gardening equipment and smaller appliances.  They buy less sporting equipment like boats, golf equipment, tennis equipment – you name it – simply because of the scarcity of resources for using such.

When two nations grossly disparate in population density atttempt to trade freely with each other, the work of manufacturing is spread evenly across the combined labor force, but the disparity in per capita consumption remains.  They buy less from us than we buy from them.  The result is inescapable – a trade deficit and loss of jobs for the less densely populated nation.  In effect, a host-parasite relationship is established in which the more densely populated nation feeds on the market of the other nation.  The less densely populated nation pays the price for the other nation’s overpopulation.  It hardly seems fair, does it?


Population Density Factor in Trade Intensifies in 2012

March 29, 2014

My apologies for taking so long to publish this data.  Trade data for 2012 was published by the government almost a year ago.  But it’s no small task to take hundreds of end use codes for nearly 200 countries and sift out the data for manufactured goods.  (It’s one of the reasons I haven’t posted as much lately – trying to finish this project, not to mention some personal projects here at home.)  The data for 2013 was released on March 1st, and I’ve already gotten a good start there. 

With that said, here’s the chart that summarizes this data, updated through 2012:  Deficits Above & Below Median Pop Density.  This chart shows America’s balance of trade in manufactured goods in 2012, split between those nations with population densities above the global median, and those nations below the global median.  (Because we’re using the median, that means that there are exactly the same number of nations on either side of the chart.)  If population density was not a factor in trade, then one would expect the balance of trade with both groups to be about the same. 

But exactly the opposite is true.  The effect of population density is enormous and undeniable.  In 2012, with the more densely populated half of nations, the U.S. experienced a trade deficit in manufactured goods of $624 billion, an increase of $47 billion over 2011, and the worst deficit since I began tracking this data in 2005.  Aside from 2009, when the global recession cut overall global trade, this figure has worsened every year. 

By contrast, in 2012 the U.S. enjoyed a surplus of trade in manufactured goods of $136 billion with the half of nations below the global median population density, a reduction of $17 billion from 2011.  This surplus appears to be leveling off. 

The net trade deficit in manufactured goods rose in 2012 to $488 billion, an increase of $64 billion over 2011, and an increase of $111 billion since 2009, the year that President Obama took office, elected in large part to fulfill his promise of reducing America’s trade deficit.

It’s impossible to overestimate the importance of this data.  It’s absolute, undeniable proof that population density is the biggest factor in driving our trade deficit, in the loss of U.S. manufacuring jobs, in the growth of our national debt, in the slow decline in our standard of living and, indeed, in virtually all of the ills that plague our economy. 

For those new to this site and unacquainted with the inverse relationship between population density and per capita consumption, a brief explanation is in order.  When two nations grossly disparate in population density attempt to trade freely with each other, the work of manufacturing is spread more or less evenly across the combined labor force.  But the disparity in per capita consumption created by the disparity in population density remains.  The result is an almost inevitable shift in manufacturing jobs toward the more densely populated nation and a corresponding trade deficit and loss of jobs for the less densely populated nation.  It’s easiest to understand if you consider the extreme – trade with a nation so densely populated that their per capita consumption is nearly zero.  In such a case, spreading the work of manufacturing evenly across the labor force will shift nearly all manufacturing jobs to that nation, while the other nation gains no corresponding market for its products.  The trade deficit exists not because the more densely populated nation manufactures and exports too much, but because it consumes too little.

We’ll look more deeply into the population density effect on U.S. trade in 2012 in upcoming posts over the next few days and weeks.  And we’ll examine whether the other factors often blamed for our trade deficit – cheap labor and currency valuations – really played any role at all.  In the meantime, my work of compiling the 2013 data is underway.  Stay tuned.


Exports Lag Obama’s Goal by Record Margin in January

March 11, 2014

http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/international/trade/2014/pdf/trad0114.pdf

The Bureau of Economic Analysis released January’s trade results on Friday – results that were consistent with reports for the past several years.  The overall trade deficit was $39.1 billion – about the same as four years earlier, thanks to the increase in exports being matched by an increase in imports. 

But four years ago, President Obama set a goal of doubling exports in five years.  With only one year left, exports have risen by only 34%.  The $48.8 billion increase in exports during that time was more than offset by a $49.8 billion increase in imports.  In order to keep pace with the president’s goal, exports needed to rise by $106.3 billion by this time.  The shortfall of $57.5 billion is a record. 

Of course, jobs are concentrated in the category of manufactured products, and there the news is even worse.  The deficit in manufactured products has worsened by 50% in the last four years.  A $24 billion increase in manufactured exports has been swamped by a $37.2 billion increase (per month) in imports.  Manufactured exports in January were less than in March of 2012.  Here’s the chart:  Manf’d exports vs. goal.  And, though the balance of trade in manufactured goods improved by $3 billion over December, the overall trend is down – sharply.  Here’s the chart:  Manf’d Goods Balance of Trade.   Manufactured exports in January fell short of the president’s goal by $40.2 billion.  The result is that absolutely no progress has been made in bringing American jobs back home.  Clearly, the “manufacturing renaissance” he boasts of is an illusion. 

In fact, the blame for the entire trade deficit now lies squarely on President Obama’s refusal to deal with the import issue.  But he seems fine with all of this.  He’s done absolutely nothing to adjust trade policy, except to make matters worse.  In March of 2012, he signed a new trade deal with South Korea which he hailed as a big win for American workers.  The result?  Our deficit with S. Korea grew by 25% in 2013 over 2012, and it’s 100% worse than the deficit only three years earlier  in 2010. 

Our only consolation is that “four more years” is now down to only (?) three more years.


Unemployment Rises in February

March 10, 2014

http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.nr0.htm

As announced by the Bureau of Labor Statistics on Friday (link to the report provided above), unemployment rose by 0.1% to 6.7%, reflecting a gain in the employment level (household survey) of only 42,000 while the labor force grew by 264,000.  This leaves per capita employment essentially unchanged in February at 45.7%.  That figure is almost 3% lower than in 2007, meaning that nearly 10 million workers remain unemployed.

Per Capita Employment

Unemployed Americans

Wall Street drew some comfort from the fact that the number of jobs created – 175,000 (according to the establishment survey) – exceeded expectations reduced by the bad weather in February, but the numbers are weak nonetheless.  Other indications of a weak job market included:

  • the number of long-term unemployed increased by 203,000 in February to 3.8 million,
  • the employment-to-population ratio hasn’t improved in the past year,
  • the number of people working part-time because they can’t find full-time employment remains at 7.2 million workers,
  • manufacturing added no new jobs in February,
  • the average work week dropped by 0.1 hours, and
  • factory overtime also declined by 0.1 hours while the average factory work week remained unchanged.

It’s yet another corroboration of the “new normal,” chronically-high unemployment economy that dumb trade policy and a growing population have given us.


Rice for Vehicles

February 21, 2014

http://www.reuters.com/article/2014/02/21/us-usa-asia-tpp-idUSBREA1K0A320140221

This epitomizes what’s wrong with American trade policy and the American economy as a whole.  As reported in the above-linked Reuters article, President Obama is running around the world selling meat and produce and is willing to surrender manufacturing jobs as payment.  In the case of Japan, he wants them to lower their tariffs on American farm products and, in return, is considering giving up our small tariffs on their cars and our big tariffs on imported trucks.  (By the way, in case you wonder whether tariffs work, take a look around at how few imported trucks are on the road compared to cars.)

At the same time that he’s marketing the U.S. as some rural, agrarian society – something we haven’t been for a century, he’s desperate to liberalize immigration policy to turn us into even more of an urban jungle than we’ve already become. 

Is the condition of our economy any wonder, when our president considers rice for vehicles an even exchange?  Does he not understand the difference in the labor involved in producing these products?  Can’t he acknowledge what a disaster the same trade deal with South Korea has been for American jobs? 

God help us.  Obama won’t.


Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 44 other followers